标签:
杂谈 |
Modern Macroeconomics in
Practice:
理论是如何成为货币政策的(第二部分)
Bernanke et al. (1999) argue that inflation targeting is moving
toward a rule-based regime. Their idea (p. 24) is that
“inflation targeting requires an accounting to
the public of the projected long run implications of its short run
policy actions.” This accounting can help
ameliorate the time inconsistency problem by ensuring that the
long-run implications of short-run policy actions are explicitly
taken into account in the policymaking process.
In practice, inflation targeting often involves setting bands of
acceptable inflation rates. (See, for example, Bernanke and
Mishkin, 1997.) In theoretical models without private information,
optimal policy does not involve setting bands, but rather involves
specifying exactly what the monetary authority should do in every
state. In this sense, such models imply that the monetary authority
should have no discretion. Athey, Atkeson, and Kehoe (2005)
construct a model in which the monetary authority has private
information about the economy and show that the optimal policy
allows for limited discretion in that it specifies acceptable
ranges for inflation and gives the monetary authority complete
discretion within those ranges. In this way, Athey, Atkeson, and
Kehoe provide a theoretical rationale for the type of inflation
targeting often seen in practice.
Perhaps the most vivid example of both the movement toward
independence and the movement toward a rule-based method of
policymaking is to be found in the charter of the European Central
Bank (ECB). Article 105 of the treaty establishing the central bank
states that “the primary
objective” of the European System of Central
Banks (ESCB) shall be to “maintain price
stability.” Article 107 of the treaty emphasizes
and protects the independence of the central bank by mandating that
“neither the ECB, nor a national central bank,
nor any member of their decision-making bodies shall seek or take
instructions from Community institutions or bodies, from any
government of a Member State or from any other
body.” Furthermore, the Maastricht Treaty and the
Stability and Growth Pact contain provisions restricting fiscal
policies in the member countries in order to make the pursuit of
price stability easier.2 The change in the conduct of European monetary policy
is especially marked for countries other than Germany in the
European monetary union.
Over the last 20 years, monetary policy in the United Kingdom has
also moved in the direction of greater independence as well as
toward rule-based policymaking. After experiencing a major exchange
rate crisis, the United Kingdom adopted a form of inflation
targeting in October 1992. In May 1997 (and subsequently formalized
by the Bank of England Act of 1998), the Bank of England gained
operational independence from the government. The Bank of England
is now specifically required primarily to pursue price stability
and only secondarily to make sure that its policies are consistent
with the growth and employment objectives of the government. The
government periodically sets an inflation target, currently 2
percent, and the central bank is given broad freedom in achieving
this target. As part of the inflation target, the government also
sets ranges for acceptable fluctuations in inflation. If inflation
moves outside its target range, the central bank is required to
report on the causes for this deviation, the corrective policy
action the central bank plans to take, and the time period within
which inflation is expected to return to its target range.
The movement toward rule-based monetary policy is widespread. By
2002, 22 countries had adopted monetary frameworks that emphasize
inflation targeting (Truman, 2003). The following countries are
listed by the date in which inflation targeting was adopted (and in
some cases readopted): in 1989, New Zealand; in 1990, Chile; in
1991, Canada and Israel; in 1992, the United Kingdom; in 1993,
Australia, Finland, and Sweden; in 1995, Spain and Mexico; in 1997,
Czech Republic and Israel (again); in 1998, Poland and Korea; in
1999, Brazil, Chile (again), and Colombia; in 2000, Thailand and
South Africa; in 2001, Hungary, Iceland, and Norway; in 2002, Peru
and the Philippines. These countries have all openly published
their inflation targets and have described their monetary framework
as one of targeting inflation. Clearly, inflation targeting is
worldwide; the countries range from developed economies to emerging
market economies. The number of countries adopting inflation
targeting is growing over time.
The first country to adopt inflation targeting, New Zealand, has
gone the furthest in setting up a rule-based regime. Before 1989,
monetary policy in New Zealand was far from being rule-based. As
Nicholl and Archer (1992, p. 316) describe:
New Zealand experienced double digit inflation for most of the period since the first oil shock. Cumulative inflation (on a Consumer Price Index (CPI) basis) between 1974 and 1988 (inclusive) was 480 percent. ... Throughout the period, monetary policy faced multiple and varying objectives which were seldom clearly specified, and only rarely consistent with achievement of inflation reduction.
In 1989, the government of New Zealand adopted legislation
mandating that the objective of the central bank be to maintain a
stable general level of prices. The government and the governor of
the central bank must agree to a policy target, which specifies an
acceptable range for inflation. Since the act was adopted, the
inflation rate has fallen considerably and has been well below 5
percent per year over the last decade or so.
Figure
2 displays the inflation experiences for four
countries—the United
Kingdom, New Zealand, Canada, and Sweden—that
have adopted inflation targeting. The four panels of Figure 2 show
the inflation rates before and after the date of the inflation
targeting regime, marked by a vertical line. The bands in the
figure following the adoption of the inflation targeting regime
depict ranges of inflation as specified in the regime. Although the
countries did not always remain within the target range for
inflation after adopting inflation targeting, inflation fell
substantially in all the countries after the adoption of inflation
targeting. The literature contains ongoing controversy about
whether this decline was solely due to inflation targeting, but
also offers substantial consensus that inflation targeting played
an important role in the decline.
Even in countries that have not explicitly adopted inflation
targeting, the institutional framework for the conduct of monetary
policy has changed in a way consistent with modern macroeconomic
theory. In the United States, for example, the central bank has
been moving toward openness and targeting for the last 25 years.
The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (commonly
referred to as the Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment Act) required
the Federal Reserve Board of Governors to report periodically to
Congress on the planned course of monetary policy. Furthermore, the
Federal Reserve Board has changed some policies in ways that
increase transparency. For example, the minutes of Federal Open
Market Committee meetings are now released substantially sooner
than they used to be, and the FOMC’s decisions
regarding its interest rate target are now released immediately
after the meeting. A large academic literature motivated by Taylor
(1993) argues that the Fed has effectively moved toward a
rule-based regime and is therefore well placed to solve the time
inconsistency problem.
Although the changes in the practice of monetary policy documented
above cannot be definitively linked to the recent theoretical
developments in macroeconomics, the most straightforward
explanation for these changes is that they are due to the
identification of the time inconsistency problem by macroeconomic
theorists.
Extending the Bounds of Macroeconomics
Macroeconomic theorists have long focused on frictions in the
labor market as a source and propagation mechanism for business
cycles. Over the last few years, a significant focus of
macroeconomic research has been the effects of government policies
on the secular trends of labor markets. The distinguishing feature
of this research is that it is based on quantitative general
equilibrium models along the lines inspired by Kydland and Prescott
(1982). Although the work in this area has not yet progressed to
definitive policy prescriptions, it is beginning to offer powerful
insights into what may have caused some problems in labor markets
and what sorts of policy changes might be part of the
solutions.
An issue that has captured much scientific and popular attention
has been the recent stubbornly high rates of unemployment in
Europe. Figure 3 shows the behavior of average unemployment rates
in Europe and the United States from 1956 to 2003. Until the late
1970s, unemployment was roughly two percentage points lower in
Europe than in the United States. Since about 1980, European
unemployment increased significantly while U.S. unemployment
decreased. By 2003, unemployment averaged more than 9 percent in
Europe, compared with only about 5 percent in the United
States.
Another way to examine labor markets is to focus on employment rates, measured as the annual average hours worked per adult of working age. Figure 4 displays the behavior of this measure of employment rates in Europe and the United States from 1956 to 2003. According to this figure, employment steadily declined over the entire period in Europe, whereas in the United States, it was roughly stable until the 1980s and then sharply increased.
Figures 3 & 4: Unemployment
and Employment |